12月1日上午游雯教授讲座:食品消费与食品健康讲座

文章来源:经贸学院 作者: 发布时间:2015-11-23 浏览次数:297
主题:Incorporating  Time  Costs  into  SNAP  Allotment  Calculation:  A  Home  Food Production  Time  Use  Analysis 
主讲人:游雯 Associate  Professor,  Department  of  Agriculture  and  Applied  Economics, Virginia  Tech
讲座时间:2015年12月1日 10:00~11:30
讲座地点:信息楼530
讲座内容:

The  Supplemental  Nutrition  Assistance  Program  (SNAP),  formerly  known  as  the 
Food  Stamp  Program,  serves  as  the  largest  hunger  safety  nest  in  the  United  States. 
The  program  aims  at  enabling  low-­‐income  eligible  people  to  purchase  foods  needed 
for  a  nutritionally  adequate  diet  through  providing  monthly  benefits  pre-­‐calculated 
for  achieving  the  goal.   In  2014,  the  program  served  about  47  million  people  with  a 
total  program  cost  of  about  $74  billion.  The  average  monthly  benefits  in  2014  were 
around  $125  per  person  and  $256  per  household  (FNS,  2015a).  Thorough 
evaluations  of  the  SNAP  program  effectiveness  at  achieving  its  goals  (i.e.,  achieving 
food  security  and  healthier  diets)  are  wanted  given  the  sizable  program  costs  and 
are  essential  for  utilizing  the  vast  coverage  of  SNAP  program  to  achieve  the  largest 
public  health  impact. 
Several  proposals  and  calls  for  actions  have  been  brought  to  the  spotlight:  such 
as  proposing  different  versions  of  SNAP  program  modifications  through  imposing 
restrictions  on  food  purchased  using  SNAP  benefits  (e.g.,You  et  al.,  2012;  Pomeranz 
and  Chriqui,  2015)  and  providing  incentives  for  healthy  food  purchasing  (e.g., 
Olshoa  et  al.,  2015;  FNS  2014c).  All  of  those  theoretical  predictions  and  field 
experiments  focused  on  whether  or  not  the  arbitrary  chosen  “boosts”  (no  matter  it 
is  in  the  form  of  rewards  or  punishment)  have  significant  impact  on  SNAP 
participants’  food  security  and  health  outcome  improvements.  However  there  is  a 
remaining  unanswered  question:  how  much  of  the  maximum  SNAP  allotment  should 
be  adjusted  to  address  the  majority  of  the  potential  inadequacy  at  reaching  SNAP 
program  goals? 
In  2013,  the  Institute  of  Medicine/National  Research  Council  committee 
published  a  report  per  the  United  States  Department  of  Agriculture  (USDA)  request 
specifically  on  addressing  the  SNAP  benefit  adequacy.   The  report  identifies  a  set  of 
adequacy-­‐relevant  factors  and  calls  for  research  to  directly  incorporate  those 
factors  into  the  SNAP  allotment  calculations  (IOM/NRC,  2013).  The  three  key  factors 
identified  by  the  committee  that  are  currently  absent  from  the  benefit  calculation 
are:  time  required  to  shop  and  prepare  food  at  home,  price  variation  across  regions 
and  unequal  access  to  healthy  food.   The  ignorance  of  time  factor  has  been 
recognized  in  the  literature  as  a  significant  road-­‐block  for  SNAP  to  achieve  its 
nutritional  goals  (Rose  2007;  You  et  al.,  2009;  Davis  and  You  2010a,  2010b,  2011, 
2013;  Rashcke  2012;  Davis  2014)  and  is  the  focus  of  this  paper. 
The  time  (labor)  cost  absent  from  the  calculation  is  an  important  oversight  since 
labor  is  an  inseparable  part  of  at-­‐home  food  production.  Ignoring  labor  (time)  cost 
will  lead  to  an  overly  optimistic  evaluation  of  SNAP  program’s  effectiveness  of 
reaching  nutrition  goals:  the  number  of  people  not  reaching  the  SNAP  program 
nutrition  goals  will  be  underestimated  or  stated  alternatively,  the  number  of  people 
classified  as  meeting  the  target  will  be  over  estimated.  This  study  calculates  the 
appropriate  scaling  factor,  k,  which  can  be  used  to  adjust  the  SNAP  benefit  amount 
so  that  the  benefit  amounts  are  consistent  with  the  Money-­‐Time  Threshold  implied 
by  the  Thrifty  Food  Plan  (which  is  the  base  for  SNAP  benefit  calculation).   The 
Money-­‐Time  Threshold  (MT)  formula  is:  !" = ! !"# + !! !"# − !! !"#$!% ,  where  M TFP 
is  the  actual  SNAP  benefit  according  to  TFP,  p  is  the  opportunity  cost  of  time,  T TFP  is 
the  TFP  implied  home  food  production  time  and  the  T actual  is  the  actual  home  food 
production  time  by  households.   This  study  looks  at  how  much  a  scaling  factor  k  can 
be  used  in  order  to  increase  the  SNAP  benefit,  M TFP ,  to  match  the  MT  threshold 
requirement.   In  other  words,  it  will  seek  to  satisfy:  !" = ! !"# ×(1 + !).   After 
substituting  the  MT  formula,  we  get  the  following  formula  for  k:  ! = !(! !"# −
! !"#$!% )/! !"# .  
This  study  utilizes  American  Time  Use  Survey  (ATUS)  data  to  get  information  on 
T actual .   For  single-­‐headed  households,  the  respondent  time  use  data  can  be  treated 
as  the  T actual  if  the  respondent  is  the  main  food  preparer  and  main  food  shopper 
which  we  utilize  information  provided  by  Eating  and  Health  Module  (EHM) 
supplement  to  ATUS  to  identify.  For  dual-­‐headed  households,  the  missing  spousal 
time  use  information  requires  imputation.   We  present  an  algorithm  to  be  used  to 
predict  spousal  food  production  time  use  information  using  information  provided  in 
ATUS  respondents’  time  use  and  spousal  demographic  and  employment  information 
along  with  the  EHM  food  production  role  identification  information. 
The  sample  was  restricted  to  those  households  with  one  or  two  adults  to  avoid 
predicting  other  adults’  time  use  since  we  do  not  have  any  further  information  on 
other  adults  of  the  households.   We  further  limit  the  sample  to  those  households 
indicating  that  their  household  income  is  less  than  or  equal  to  185%  of  the  poverty 
threshold  since  the  focus  of  scaling  the  SNAP  benefits  is  to  help  low-­‐income 
households.   We  further  drop  households  with  respondent  indicating  that  he/she  is 
sharing  the  food  production  roles  with  other  adults  in  the  household  since  there  is 
no  information  available  to  assume  the  percentage  split  of  the  responsibility. 
Two-­‐part  models  are  utilized  to  estimate  and  predict  time  use  based  on  food 
production  role  differences  and  the  scaling  factor  k  is  calculated  for  the  following 
four  categories  of  households:  single-­‐headed  households  with  children,  single-­‐
headed  households  without  children,  dual-­‐headed  households  with  children,  dual-­‐
headed  household  without  children.  To  account  for  the  uncertainty  in  the 
opportunity  cost  of  time,  p,  and  the  estimation  noises  in  the  actual  time  use, 
parametric  bootstrapping  is  conducted  to  map  out  the  empirical  distribution  for  the 
k  factor. 
We  find  that  ignoring  spousal  contribution  to  household  food  production 
underestimates  household  home  food  production  time  by  about  3  hours  per  week.  
Without  considering  the  spousal  contribution  to  food  production  time,  we  are  likely 
to  overestimate  the  labor  adjusted  full  TFP  cost  deficit  by  about  $50  per  week.   On 
average,  the  suggested  scaling  factor,  k,  is  less  than  0.5.   Furthermore,  we  compare 
the  adjusted  TFP  amount  with  the  Low-­‐Cost  Food  Plan  (LCFP)  amount  and 
Moderate-­‐Cost  Food  Plan  (MCFP)  amount.   The  adjusted  TFP  amount  has  much 
higher  median  than  both  LCFP  and  MCFP  for  single-­‐headed  households  with  and 
without  children.   Without  considering  spousal  contribution  to  the  production  time, 
the  dual  headed  households’  adjusted  TFP  amount  also  has  slightly  larger  median 
than  LCFP  and  MCFP.   However,  after  considering  spousal  contribution  to  the  food 
production,  the  dual  headed  households’  adjusted  TFP  amount  became  slightly 
smaller  than  the  LCFP  and  much  smaller  than  the  MCFP.   This  signals  that  dual-­‐
headed  households  have  the  flexibility  of  spousal  time  substitution  therefore  their 
time  constraints  are  not  as  tight  as  the  single-­‐headed  households  and  require 
smaller  time-­‐cost  adjustment  to  meet  the  threshold.